Pricing of orphan drugs follows the same economic logic as drug pricing in general: the price of an orphan drug is set by a manufacturer in an effort to recoup research and development (R&D) costs and to attain a certain profit margin. Additionally, the price takes into account the value of the product to the patient, market conditions (e.g. the existence of alternative health technologies) and the regulatory pricing and reimbursement environment in a country. However, the market for orphan drugs has inherent market failures, thus resulting in high prices due to a number of reasons.
Monopoly
In the EU, orphan drugs benefit from a period of marketing exclusivity following marketing authorization. Marketing exclusivity gives a monopoly to the manufacturer as no other company is allowed to market the orphan drug during the exclusivity period. The monopolistic power is strengthened by the fact that no alternative health technology exists for many orphan drugs. Additionally, marketing can further boost market power. Under these conditions, manufacturers have an incentive to charge the maximum price for an orphan drug that the market is able to bear. Health care payers have limited negotiating power, often lack information about the cost structure of orphan drugs, and are under pressure from patient advocacy groups and media to accommodate new orphan drugs [6]. As a result, health care payers are often forced to accept the price offered by the manufacturer.
For instance, a recent study compared prices of 28 designated orphan drugs with prices of 16 comparable non-designated drugs for rare disease indications [7]. Price data were based on official hospital prices (per defined daily dose) in Belgium in 2010. Orphan-designated drugs had a higher median price (€ 138.56 - IQR € 483.06) than non-designated drugs (€ 16.55 - IQR € 28.67) for rare disease indications (p < 0.01). The authors concluded that awarding orphan designation status in itself is associated with higher prices for drugs for rare disease indications.
Manufacturers can attempt to create a monopoly market by splitting up a disease into several sub-diseases that qualify as rare diseases (a practice called 'disease sub-setting', 'salami-slicing' or 'disease stratification') [8]. In other words, artificial sub-sets of a common disease are created with a view to qualifying as several rare diseases. The domains of for example pharmacogenomics and oncology are prime targets for creating new rare diseases [9]. Disease stratification may have many benefits for a manufacturer: the company can benefit from measures to stimulate the development of its products, the company creates a monopolistic market where chronically ill patients receive long-term treatment with its orphan drug, the company incurs lower marketing costs as it needs to reach fewer medical specialists, marketing exclusivity erases the possibility of 'me-too' competitors, and the small market reduces the economic viability for generic drugs [10].
The impact of monopolistic market power on prices can also be witnessed in the observation of price increases when a drug with a common indication receives a second, orphan indication. This can be illustrated with the case of sildenafil in Belgium: the orphan drug Revatio® for pulmonary arterial hypertension was more than six times more expensive than Viagra® for erectile dysfunction in 2011.
In the EU, multiple orphan drugs can be authorised to diagnose, prevent or treat a specific rare disease. As a result, the monopolistic power of an orphan drug is sometimes offset by the availability of other products and competitive pressures may reduce prices. For instance, advanced renal cell carcinoma and cystic fibrosis each have ten drugs with designated orphan status [11]. Using available data on the annual cost per patient of reimbursed orphan drugs in Belgium and the availability of alternative health technologies [4], 13 orphan drugs with an alternative had a lower annual cost per patient than 9 orphan drugs without an alternative, although this finding was not statistically significant (independent samples t-test; p = 0.183).
Price variation between countries
A study compared prices of ten orphan drugs between 25 EU countries [3]. Price data originated from pharmaceutical industry, health authorities, retail or hospital pharmacies, and national databases. The authors noted that some domestic pricing and reimbursement policies provide incentives to maximise prices of orphan drugs. Countries that adhere to free market pharmaceutical pricing generally have higher drug prices and, thus, higher prices for orphan drugs (e.g. Germany) than countries that regulate prices (e.g. Portugal, Spain). Prices of orphan drugs distributed through the hospital pharmacy are not regulated in most European countries, but are negotiated between the manufacturer and an individual hospital. To have a stronger negotiating position, some hospitals jointly purchase orphan drugs from manufacturers. Also, countries such as Belgium, Greece and Italy have imposed price controls on orphan drugs distributed through the hospital pharmacy. Manufacturers are free to set prices of orphan drugs in the United Kingdom, although the Pharmaceutical Price Regulation Scheme (which regulates industry profitability rather than drug prices) [12] and pharmaco-economic guidelines exert downward pressure on prices of orphan drugs. Although the National Institute for Health and Clinical Excellence in England does not frequently appraise orphan drugs, the Scottish Medicines Consortium and the All Wales Medicines Strategy Group do appraise orphan drugs, with the latter for example having specific guidelines for appraising orphan drugs and ultra-orphan drugs [13]. In France, the system of authorization for temporary use allows manufacturers to freely set and maximise the price for an orphan drug which will be fully reimbursed.
Costs of R&D and market access
The high price of orphan drugs also derives from the cost of the R&D process and of market access procedures. R&D of drugs is a very expensive process associated with a high attrition rate of potential products. Furthermore, in the case of orphan drugs, these R&D costs need to be recouped from a small number of patients, thus resulting in high acquisition costs per patient [14]. A European analysis of orphan drug prices in 25 countries found that the price of an orphan drug is higher for a disease with a lower prevalence [3]. Using published data on the annual cost per patient of an orphan drug in Belgium [4] and the prevalence of the rare disease as derived from Orphanet [15], Figure 1 points to a negative association between the cost of an orphan drug and the prevalence of the disease (y = 26230x-0,5316; R2 = 0.468). A similar inverse association has also been observed using Italian data [16].
However, the need to recoup substantial R&D costs from a small number of patients does not apply to all orphan drugs. Some orphan drugs were approved on the basis of historical use, where the manufacturer was not required to produce new evidence on efficacy to gain marketing authorization. In such cases, R&D costs are small. The provision to license drugs without much industry-investment in clinical trials can be illustrated with the case of amifampridine (3,4-diaminopyridine phosphate), which is approved for Lambert-Eaton syndrome. The clinical evidence underpinning this orphan drug primarily referred to the literature on the free base form of 3,4-diaminopyridine [17].
With respect to market access procedures, a recent study showed that orphan drugs were less likely to gain marketing authorization from EMA than other drugs [18]. Furthermore, manufacturers have to comply with different pricing and reimbursement procedures in each member state, thereby raising the price of orphan drugs [10]. Another driver of orphan drug prices occurs following marketing authorization. As many orphan drugs are fast-tracked to market authorization (due to, for example, the life-threatening nature of the disease and the absence of alternative health technologies), regulatory authorities tend to impose expensive post-marketing surveillance programmes.
Many orphan drugs target few patients as they are used to treat rare or ultra-rare diseases, the prevalence of which is generally ill-researched. Also, not all patients are diagnosed or need treatment [5]. Nevertheless, the assertion that orphan drugs target few patients does not apply to all cases [19]. First, certain orphan drugs have proved to be effective against multiple rare diseases and, thus, target a larger number of patients. Examples are sorafenib, which has been approved by the EMA to treat patients with hepatocellular carcinoma and advanced renal cell carcinoma; and imatinib, which has six designated orphan indications in the EU. Second, the use of an orphan drug for a rare disease may subsequently be extended to a common disease. Bosentan, an orphan drug for the treatment of pulmonary arterial hypertension, may also be effective to treat heart failure [20]. Third, a drug for a common disease may subsequently develop an indication for a rare disease. An example is sildenafil, whose initial indication of erectile dysfunction was later extended to include pulmonary artery hypertension and chronic thromboembolic pulmonary hypertension. Fourth, while a disease may qualify as a rare disease in one country, it may be more common in other countries (e.g. drugs to treat tropical diseases). Furthermore, a common disease in one country (e.g. Balkan nephropathy) may qualify as a rare disease at EU level [11]. Finally, although these diseases are individually rare, rare diseases collectively affect approximately 30 million Europeans [6].
Economic viability
Legislation in the EU attempts to address the issue of the price and the economic viability of orphan drugs. EU legislation is in place to reduce the period of marketing exclusivity if an orphan drug turns out to be sufficiently profitable [1]. However, it is not clear what is meant by 'sufficiently profitable' and this legislation has never been put into practice. The lack of economic viability of orphan drugs can be questioned in certain cases. Some orphan drugs probably do not require a high level of investment to market the drug. For instance, the costs of extending the indication of sildenafil to pulmonary artery hypertension and chronic thromboembolic pulmonary hypertension are likely to be limited to conducting clinical trials and to marketing.
Orphan biopharmaceuticals
Many orphan drugs (in development) are made by or derived from living organisms using biotechnology. A study focused on ex-manufacturer prices of biopharmaceuticals in five European countries (France, Germany, Italy, Spain, and the United Kingdom), Australia, Canada, Japan, Mexico, and the United States [21]. The authors argued that biopharmaceutical prices may be less regulated and higher than those of chemically-derived drugs given that: a) some countries exclude biopharmaceuticals used in hospital from price regulation; b) price comparisons with other products in a therapeutic class are less likely to occur for biopharmaceuticals with a novel mechanism of action or indication; c) informal cost-effectiveness thresholds may be higher for biopharmaceuticals that address unmet clinical needs or that treat rare diseases; and d) some countries have in place industrial policies to support the development of biopharmaceuticals.
When the 20-year patent on a biopharmaceutical expires, less expensive versions of the drug, so-called biosimilar drugs or follow-on biologics, can enter the market. Orphan biopharmaceuticals tend to face limited competition from biosimilars due to difficulties in and the costs of demonstrating bio-similarity. To substantiate the claim of biosimilarity in Europe, the manufacturer must conduct a direct and extensive comparability exercise between the biosimilar and the reference biopharmaceutical, with a view to demonstrating that the two products have similar quality, safety and efficacy.